Factor Proportions Theory Explained

Updated on March 13, 2018
saif113sb profile image

Saif writes about inflation, deflation, laws of supply and demand, and other important economics-related topics.

Source

Factor Proportions Theory

Trade theory, like all of economic theory, changed drastically in the first half of the twentieth century. The factor proportions theory developed by the Swedish economist Eli Heckscher, and later expanded by his former graduate student Bertil Ohlin, formed the major theory of international trade and is still widely accepted today. Whereas Smith and Ricardo emphasized a labor theory of value, the factor proportions theory is based on a more modern concept of production that raises capital to the same level of importance as labor.

Factor Intensity in Production

The factor intensity in production theory is a two-dimensional concept and includes labor and capital. Technology determines the way labor and capital combine to form a product. Different products require different proportions of these two factors of production.

It is easy to see how the factor proportions of the production of a product differs substantially among groups of products. For example, the manufacturing of leather footwear is still a relatively labor-intensive process, even with the most sophisticated leather treatment and patterning machinery. Other products, such as computer memory chips, still require some highly skilled labor, but rely more on massive quantities of capital for production, development, and facilities. The concept of factor proportions is very useful in the comparison of the production processes of goods.

According to factor proportions theory, factor intensities depend on the state of technology and the current method of manufacturing of a given product. The theory assumes that the same technology of production would be used for the same goods in all countries. It is not, therefore, differences in the efficiency of production that will determine trade between countries, as it did in classical theory. Classical theory implicitly assumed that technology, or the productivity of labor, is different across countries. Otherwise, there would be no logical explanation as to why one country would require more units of labor to produce a unit of output than another country. Factor proportions theory assumed no such productivity differences.

Factor Endowments, Factor Prices, and Comparative Advantage

If there is no difference in technology or productivity of factors across countries, what, then, determines comparative advantage in production and export? The answer is that factor prices determine cost differences. These prices are determined by the endowments of labor and capital the country possesses. The theory assumes that labor and capital are immobile, meaning they cannot move across country borders. Therefore, a country's endowment determines the relative costs of labor and capital as compared to other countries.

Each country is defined or measured by the amount of labor and capital that it possesses. If a country has, when compared to other countries, more labor and less capital, it would be characterized as relatively labor abundant. That which is more plentiful is cheaper. Thus, a labor-abundant country would have relatively cheap labor.

A country such as China possesses a relatively large endowment of labor and a smaller endowment of capital. Japan is a relatively capital-abundant country with a smaller endowment of labor. China possesses cheaper labor and should therefore specialize in the production and export of labor-intensive products. Japan possesses relatively cheap capital and should specialize in the production and export of capital-intensive products. The comparative advantage is derived not from the productivity of a country, but from the relative abundance of its factors of production.

Operating with these assumptions, the factor proportions theory states that a country should specialize in the production and export of those products that make use of its relatively abundant factor.

  1. A country that is relatively labor abundant should specialize in the production of relatively labor intensive goods. It should then export these labor intensive goods in exchange for capital intensive goods.
  2. A country that is relatively capital abundant should specialized in the production of relatively capital intensive goods. It should then export these capital intensive goods in exchange for labor intensive goods.

The Leontief Paradox

One of the most famous tests of any economic or business theory occurred in 1960, when economist Wisely Leontief tested whether the factor proportions theory could be used to explain the types of goods the United States imported and exported.

Leontief's premise was based on a widely shared view that some countries, such as the U.S., were endowed with large amounts of capital equipment, while other countries were short on capital but well-endowed with large amounts of labor. Thus, it was thought that a country with significant capital would be more efficient in producing capital-intensive products, and that a country with large amounts of labor would be more efficient in producing labor-intensive products.

Leontief had to devise a method to determine the relative amounts of labor and capital in a product. His solution, known as input-output analysis, was an accomplishment on its own. Input-output analysis is a technique of breaking down products into the amounts and costs of the labor, capital, and other potential factors employed in the product's manufacture. Leontief then used this method to analyze the labor and capital content of all U.S. merchandise imports and exports. The hypothesis was relatively straight forward: U.S. exports should be more capital-intensive than U.S. imports. Leontief's results were, however, a bit of a shock.

Leontief found that the products that U.S. firms exported were more labor-intensive than the products the U.S. imported8. It seemed that if the factor proportions theory were true, the U.S. would be identified as a relatively labor-abundant country. Alternatively, the theory could be wrong. Neither interpretation of the results was acceptable to many in the field of international trade research.

A variety of explanations and continuing studies have attempted to solve what has become known as the Leontief Paradox. It was first thought to have been simply a result of the specific year when the study was conducted, which was 1946. However, the same results were found when the theory was applied to different years and data sets. The next explanation was that Leontief did not really analyze the labor and capital contents of imports, but rather the labor and capital content was actually producing these products in a more capital-intensive fashion than the countries from which it imported manufactured goods. Finally, the debate turned to the need for analysts to distinguish different types of labor and capital. Several studies attempted to separate labor factors into skilled labor and unskilled labor. These studies have continued to show results more consistent with what the factor proportions theory would suggest. In the 1970s, a number of studies expanded the factors of production to include energy, particularly oil, as a factor of production that would explain the paradox. The results to date have been mixed, at best.

Linder's Overlapping Product Ranges Theory

The difficulty in confirming the factor proportions theory led many scholars in the 1960s and 1970s to search for new explanations of why countries trade with each other. The work of Staffan Burenstam Linder focused on the preferences of consumers, or demand, rather than production or supply.

Linder argued that trade in manufactured goods was dictated not by cost, but by the demand for similar types of products across countries. His theory was based on two principles:

  1. As per capita income rises the complexity and quality level of products demanded by a country's residents also rises. The range of product sophistication demanded by a country's residents is largely determined by its level of income.
  2. The business firms that produce a society's need are more knowledgeable about their domestic markets than foreign markets. The firms could not be expected to effectively service a foreign market that is significantly different from the domestic market because the ability to compete comes from experience in the home market. A logical pattern would be for the firm to gain success and market share at home first, and then expand to foreign markets that have a demand for similar products.

Global trade in manufactured goods among nations would then be influenced by the demand for similar products. The countries that would engage in the most intensive trade would be those with similar per capita income levels, for they would possess a greater likelihood of overlapping when it comes to product demands. For example, the U.S. and Canada, which have similar per capita income levels, have consumer product demands for similar products when it comes to complexity and quality.

By comparison, the U.S. and Mexico have significantly different per capita income levels and, as such, might be anticipated to have dissimilar consumer product demands. The conclusions drawn from Linder's theory differed from the cost-oriented theories that preceded it: The most intensive trade would exist between countries of the same income or industrialization levels, and a large part of global trade would be referred to as intraindustry trade, which is the exchange of essentially identical goods between countries, such as the U.S. exporting automobiles to Europe and, at the same time, Europe exporting automobiles to the U.S.

© 2011 saif113sb

Comments

    0 of 8192 characters used
    Post Comment

    • profile image

      master 12 months ago

      now l can write my exam

    • lionel1 profile image

      lionel1 6 years ago

      Thank you for you in depth post on 'Factor Proportions Theory' it's all new to me, but I found it very interesting.

    • chefsref profile image

      Lee Raynor 6 years ago from Citra Florida

      Hey Saif

      Is factor theory something used by businesses for planning, or is it just a way to explain what has already happened?

      I think the perhaps unintended outcome of global trade is that we (in the USA) are seeing our standard of living decline while China, India, et al are raising theirs at our expense. Are we in a zero sum game?

    working

    This website uses cookies

    As a user in the EEA, your approval is needed on a few things. To provide a better website experience, owlcation.com uses cookies (and other similar technologies) and may collect, process, and share personal data. Please choose which areas of our service you consent to our doing so.

    For more information on managing or withdrawing consents and how we handle data, visit our Privacy Policy at: "https://owlcation.com/privacy-policy#gdpr"

    Show Details
    Necessary
    HubPages Device IDThis is used to identify particular browsers or devices when the access the service, and is used for security reasons.
    LoginThis is necessary to sign in to the HubPages Service.
    Google RecaptchaThis is used to prevent bots and spam. (Privacy Policy)
    AkismetThis is used to detect comment spam. (Privacy Policy)
    HubPages Google AnalyticsThis is used to provide data on traffic to our website, all personally identifyable data is anonymized. (Privacy Policy)
    HubPages Traffic PixelThis is used to collect data on traffic to articles and other pages on our site. Unless you are signed in to a HubPages account, all personally identifiable information is anonymized.
    Amazon Web ServicesThis is a cloud services platform that we used to host our service. (Privacy Policy)
    CloudflareThis is a cloud CDN service that we use to efficiently deliver files required for our service to operate such as javascript, cascading style sheets, images, and videos. (Privacy Policy)
    Google Hosted LibrariesJavascript software libraries such as jQuery are loaded at endpoints on the googleapis.com or gstatic.com domains, for performance and efficiency reasons. (Privacy Policy)
    Features
    Google Custom SearchThis is feature allows you to search the site. (Privacy Policy)
    Google MapsSome articles have Google Maps embedded in them. (Privacy Policy)
    Google ChartsThis is used to display charts and graphs on articles and the author center. (Privacy Policy)
    Google AdSense Host APIThis service allows you to sign up for or associate a Google AdSense account with HubPages, so that you can earn money from ads on your articles. No data is shared unless you engage with this feature. (Privacy Policy)
    Google YouTubeSome articles have YouTube videos embedded in them. (Privacy Policy)
    VimeoSome articles have Vimeo videos embedded in them. (Privacy Policy)
    PaypalThis is used for a registered author who enrolls in the HubPages Earnings program and requests to be paid via PayPal. No data is shared with Paypal unless you engage with this feature. (Privacy Policy)
    Facebook LoginYou can use this to streamline signing up for, or signing in to your Hubpages account. No data is shared with Facebook unless you engage with this feature. (Privacy Policy)
    MavenThis supports the Maven widget and search functionality. (Privacy Policy)
    Marketing
    Google AdSenseThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Google DoubleClickGoogle provides ad serving technology and runs an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Index ExchangeThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    SovrnThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Facebook AdsThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Amazon Unified Ad MarketplaceThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    AppNexusThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    OpenxThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Rubicon ProjectThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    TripleLiftThis is an ad network. (Privacy Policy)
    Say MediaWe partner with Say Media to deliver ad campaigns on our sites. (Privacy Policy)
    Remarketing PixelsWe may use remarketing pixels from advertising networks such as Google AdWords, Bing Ads, and Facebook in order to advertise the HubPages Service to people that have visited our sites.
    Conversion Tracking PixelsWe may use conversion tracking pixels from advertising networks such as Google AdWords, Bing Ads, and Facebook in order to identify when an advertisement has successfully resulted in the desired action, such as signing up for the HubPages Service or publishing an article on the HubPages Service.
    Statistics
    Author Google AnalyticsThis is used to provide traffic data and reports to the authors of articles on the HubPages Service. (Privacy Policy)
    ComscoreComScore is a media measurement and analytics company providing marketing data and analytics to enterprises, media and advertising agencies, and publishers. Non-consent will result in ComScore only processing obfuscated personal data. (Privacy Policy)
    Amazon Tracking PixelSome articles display amazon products as part of the Amazon Affiliate program, this pixel provides traffic statistics for those products (Privacy Policy)